Entries from October 1, 2008 - October 31, 2008

What would an "average" UK recession look like?

Posted on Thursday, October 23, 2008 at 03:36PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

One way of "benchmarking" the current recession is to compare it with an average of the last three - 1974-75, 1979-81 and 1990-91. Based on the analysis below, an average recession path would involve GDP falling by 2-2.5% between Q2 2008 and Q2 2009, moving sideways over the following year and recovering by 2.5% in the year from Q2 2010. This would imply an annual decline in GDP of 1.7% in 2009 followed by growth of just 0.4% in 2010 - significantly weaker than current consensus forecasts of -0.2% and 1.2% respectively (as reported by Consensus Economics Inc).

Economists typically use quarterly GDP data to determine the timing and magnitude of recessions. However, GDP is sometimes distorted by strikes and other disruptions to normal economic activity. For example, GDP peaked in Q2 1973 and fell in each of the subsequent three quarters but much of this weakness reflected industrial action in the coal mining industry, culminating in the three-day week in Q1 1974. The analysis below uses a strike-adjusted measure of GDP, incorporating information on working days lost in industrial action, to calculate the depth of prior recessions. In addition, a judgement is made that the mid 1970s recession began in Q4 1974 rather than Q3 1973.

The first chart overlays the path of strike-adjusted GDP before, during and after the last three recessions on the current cycle. GDP is assumed to have peaked in Q2 2008 and the prior peaks are rebased and aligned to this starting point.

When the mid 1970s recession is dated to start in 1974 rather than 1973, it looks similar in magnitude and duration to the 1990-91 decline. However, the subsequent recovery was much swifter in the 1970s, probably because sterling's membership of the ERM constrained monetary easing in the later episode.

The peak-to-trough fall in GDP was significantly larger in 1979-81 - 6.2% versus 2.8% in 1974-75 and 2.5% in 1990-91. This dismal performance, however, was the mirror-image of much stronger growth in the year before the GDP peak - 5.3% against 0.3% and 1.6% respectively. Relative to its value four quarters before the peak, GDP troughed at similar levels in 1981 and 1991, with a slightly larger decline in 1975.

This last point suggests calculating a benchmark future path by averaging the performance of GDP relative to its level four quarters before the peak across the three cycles, rather than relative to the peak itself. The result is shown in the second chart and is the basis for the description of an average recession path given earlier.

As argued in previous posts, the current recession could be less severe than the last three, because the preceding boom was smaller, interest rates have risen by less and the exchange rate has been unusually weak. Such mitigating factors, however, will be overridden if current financial paralysis persists. Detailed monetary statistics for September to be released next Wednesday will provide further information on the damage to economic prospects from the financial freeze.

 

UK rates: big follow-up cut likely in November - why wait?

Posted on Wednesday, October 22, 2008 at 11:25AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

A week before the October MPC meeting the MPC-ometer forecast a quarter-point rate cut - at odds with the majority view of no change in a Reuters poll. By the time of the decision the projection had changed to half a point, allowing for the "shock" from escalating financial turmoil - see here.

Minutes of the special MPC meeting on 8 October confirm that recent financial events have resulted in a fundamental shift in the Committee's thinking. The focus now is on averting the "tail risk" of a severe recession and significant inflation undershoot. In terms of the MPC-ometer, this shift can be captured by "switching on" the shock variable that played a key role in explaining the MPC's behaviour after the 9/11 terrorist attacks.

The model's forecast will also depend importantly on Friday's third-quarter GDP report as well as consumer and business surveys to be released around month-end. Assuming a quarterly GDP decline of 0.2% and unchanged survey responses, the -ometer suggests a three-quarter-point cut at the next meeting on 5/ 6 November.

As discussed in previous posts, an alternative version of the model assumes the MPC targets interbank interest rates rather than Bank rate. This projects a full-point Bank rate cut in November if three-month LIBOR is above 5.75% at the time of the meeting (fixed at 6.04% today).

Both versions suggest the MPC will go on hold in December and January if the November forecasts prove correct.

For comparison, the overnight indexed swap curve currently discounts a 62 basis point cut by 6 November with further falls of 14 bp in December and 17 bp in January.

US Fed embraces Japan-style "quantitative easing"

Posted on Tuesday, October 21, 2008 at 11:27AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | Comments2 Comments

Federal Reserve Bank credit - the Fed's lending to banks, dealers, other central banks and AIG plus its holdings of securities - has soared by $850 billion, or over 90%, since 11 September, just before Lehman's failure. Importantly, the Fed has chosen not to sterilise fully the impact of this expansion on banks' reserves - their deposits held at the Fed. Reserves and currency in circulation constitute the monetary base. The average level of the base in the fortnight to 8 October was 17% higher than four weeks earlier.

Real monetary base expansion tends to lead economic activity so the recent pick-up could suggest improving growth prospects - see first chart. Historically, however, major swings in base money have been driven by the currency component rather than bank reserves. The hope is that banks holding excess cash in their accounts at the Fed will be more willing to lend to other banks and the wider economy but many commentators believe the Fed is "pushing on a string".

The Fed is copying the Bank of Japan's 2001 policy of "quantitative easing", which involved the central bank buying government bonds in order to flood the banking system with liquidity. Real monetary base growth peaked at an annual 38% - see second chart. Commentators were similarly sceptical of any impact on financial behaviour or economic activity but growth recovered in 2002, while the rate of contraction of bank lending slowed, although these improvements may have reflected other factors.

UK recap scheme to curb broad money

Posted on Monday, October 20, 2008 at 02:35PM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

The UK’s bank recapitalisation plan is unlikely to lead to a near-term revival in credit and money growth. Indeed, the initial impact of the scheme will be to reduce the broad money supply M4, implying a need for offsetting monetary easing measures, including interest rate cuts.

The negative M4 impact arises because a portion of the additional gilts and Treasury bills being issued to finance the recapitalisation will be bought by the non-bank private sector, implying a transfer of money out of bank deposits included in M4 into government coffers. If the entire £37 billion were raised from private non-banks – admittedly unlikely – M4 would be cut by 2.0%, before allowing for second-round effects.

This negative impact would be offset if banks used the funds injected by the government to increase their lending. However, the aim of the scheme is to raise capital ratios to a new higher level that banks will be required to maintain over the medium term, rather than provide them with “excess” capital to support additional balance sheet expansion. In other words, any increase in lending may depend on further capital-raising – arguably made more difficult by the stringent terms of the “rescue”.

The negative impact on M4 would be avoided if the government were to fund the recapitalisation by borrowing from the Bank of England but this would be at odds with current institutional arrangements and EU Treaty obligations discouraging central bank lending to governments.

The Debt Management Office plans to increase sales of gilts and Treasury bills by £30 billion and £7 billion respectively in 2008-09. There is a strong case for boosting the amount to be raised from Treasury bills, since these are more likely to be purchased by banks themselves, thereby avoiding a transfer of funds out of M4 deposits.

Headline M4 expansion rose to an annual 12.2% in September but continues to be badly distorted by the financial crisis. Underlying growth – excluding the contribution of non-bank financial intermediaries – fell from 13.6% to 6.5% between June 2007 and June 2008 and is likely to have slipped further more recently (September data will be available in early November). Underlying M4 probably needs to expand by 6-8% per annum to keep inflation on track to meet the 2% inflation target over the medium term. (This assumes trend GDP growth of about 2.5% and a decline in M4 velocity of 2-3% pa, in line with the average over 1992-2004, when inflation was close to 2%.)

UK institutional liquidity historically high

Posted on Friday, October 17, 2008 at 10:19AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

The liquidity ratio of UK insurance companies and pension funds – their holdings of money and short-term paper expressed as a percentage of their total financial assets – is at its highest level since 1975, implying institutions have ample firepower to deploy in markets when confidence returns.

Liquidity stood at £182 billion at the end of the second quarter, £31 billion up on a year before and equivalent to 8.4% of assets, the highest since the bottom of the equity bear market in 1990 – see chart. With the subsequent fall in asset values, the ratio is now likely to be about 9.5%, above the 1990 peak and a level exceeded only in 1974-75, after a plunge in share prices of more than 70%.

The latest Merrill Lynch global fund manager survey confirms high sideline liquidity, with a net 49% of respondents overweight cash – the highest since this question began to be asked in 2001.

M1 currently best guide to monetary conditions

Posted on Thursday, October 16, 2008 at 10:36AM by Registered CommenterSimon Ward | CommentsPost a Comment

A key “monetarist” insight is that the supply of money can diverge from the money demand of households, corporations and financial institutions. “Excess” money will tend to flow into economies and markets, boosting activity and prices. Conversely, growth and asset values are at risk when money supply expansion falls short of demand.

Implementing the concept requires estimates of the growth rates of money supply and demand. The appropriate supply definition is a broad one, including currency, sight and time deposits, savings accounts and money market mutual funds. Money demand cannot be observed directly but under normal circumstances is likely to be related to the level of economic activity, which can be proxied by industrial production (available on a more frequent and timely basis than GDP).

As the chart shows, inflation-adjusted broad money growth in the Group of Seven (G7) major economies has been running well ahead of industrial output expansion in recent months but this has proved a poor guide to monetary conditions affecting economies and markets, for two reasons. First, the collapse of the “shadow” banking system has led to an enforced expansion of banks’ balance sheets, inflating published broad money numbers. (An adjusted measure – including US commercial paper – is shown in the chart but does not capture the full extent of such “reintermediation”.)

Secondly, money demand has probably been growing much faster than industrial production, as the financial crisis has prompted a flight into capital-certain liquid assets. Changes in the precautionary demand for cash are likely to be correlated with measures of investor risk aversion. These appeared to be moderating during the summer but have subsequently risen to new highs.

Given these uncertainties, narrow money M1 – comprising currency and instant-access deposits – is likely to be a better guide to monetary conditions currently than the broad money / output growth gap. Any “excess” money is likely to show up in M1 before being deployed in the economy or markets. As the chart shows, inflation-adjusted G7 M1 fell by 2% in the year to August – the largest annual contraction since 1981.

Empirical analysis indicates that changes in real M1 growth lead the economy by about six months and are roughly coincident with stock market movements. The recent slide therefore validates equity market weakness and signals a grim near-term economic outlook.

Data confirmation should be awaited but real M1 could be near a trough, reflecting three factors. First, US M1 has accelerated sharply in recent weeks. However, this appears to reflect a “safe-haven” shift out of money market mutual funds into demand deposits rather than a genuine improvement.

Secondly, M1 is inversely correlated with deposit interest rates so recent and prospective central bank easing will be supportive.

Thirdly, real trends will benefit from a big fall in headline inflation over coming months as energy and food price effects reverse dramatically.